Wednesday, 30 June 2021

What got snuck in

We only got through Day 1 of last week's NZ Association of Economists' annual workshop before the Plague shut us down, but it was interesting while it lasted (full programme here - there's a fair smattering of the papers available to download), and on the positive side at least we snuck one day in, unlike the total lockdown wipeout of 2020.

The first keynote was ecological economist Marjan van den Belt on 'Aoteanomics; A Vision for a Thriving, Just and Sustainable Aotearoa NZ' (brief abstract here). If you're a fan of, say, Kate Raworth's Doughnut Economics: Seven Ways to Think Like a 21st-Century Economist, then this was for you. I liked her emphasis on systems thinking/modelling that captures all the positive and negative aspects of any policy, and accounts for the inter-relationships between the various moving parts. 

But I didn't agree that economics as we all know and love it today isn't up to, or interested in, handling issues like climate change or other environmental degradation: you don't get far into an economics course these days without bumping into 'externalities' and how to deal with them. And she's what I might call a technology pessimist about the ability of technological change to get us out of the climate and pollution hole - "we can't efficiency our way out" as she put it - whereas I'd point to the likes of the plummeting cost of solar energy or indeed the speed with which Covid vaccines were developed. The last 20th / early 21st century is an odd time to be downbeat about inventiveness.

From the concurrent session options, I picked 'Auckland Council - Urban Economics'. The big takeaway for me was the work done by David Norman (the former chief economist for the Council) and his colleague, now acting chief economist, Shane Martin, on whether the planning constraints which apply inside the Rural Urban Boundary (RUB) are responsible for the very high prices of Auckland housing land when compared to land outside it. As an Auckland resident regularly gobsmacked by the price of land, I'd have been prepared to bet a reasonable amount of money that they did, but at least for now I've been disabused. After comparing like-for-like land (eg correcting for the value of closeness to amenities and a zillion other hedonic features) there's virtually no RUB factor, as shown below (from the version of the paper available on the Council's Economic Advice page).


After coffee it was time for Motu's Arthur Grimes on 'Reinterpreting Productivity: New Zealand’s Surprising Performance'. Well worth reading: while the stylised narrative is that New Zealand has gone to hell in a handbasket in terms of relative international performance over time, Arthur argued (pp22-3) that "The country enacted reforms in the 1980s and early 1990s that improved allocative efficiency as well as technical efficiency. The result has been one of the strongest performances of any developed country in the growth of sustainable consumption possibilities over the second 24 year period covered by our data" (i.e. the second half of 1970-2018).

In the afternoon the 'Household Economics' session had two papers looking at how extra tax credits and extended parental paid leave since 2018 had worked out (one paper is up, here): my overall impression was they made a difference (in a good way) but more could be done. Victoria's Norman Gemmell presented on behalf of his co-authors Nazila Alinaghi and John Creedy on 'Do Couples Bunch More? Evidence from Partnered and Single Taxpayers', which looked at the bunching of people's tax returns around marginal tax rate thresholds. 

There were questions from the audience suggesting that it looked like tax evasion: it isn't (or not necessarily), because (a) that's the way the tax system is, or as the paper says (p25) the system "imposes relatively weak constraints on intra-family income sharing" and (b) the income split is inherently arbitrary for self-employed couples. If one partner stays home to let the plumber in while the other goes out to meet a client, who's contributed what? It was also a reminder that while the all-knowing always-calculating homo economicus may be a caricature of how people behave, people aren't stupid, either, and are perfectly capable of making fine adjustments to their affairs to their own best advantage.

Finally I went to the 'Commerce Commission: Market outcomes in the retail fuel and electricity markets' session (natch). Quick hat-tip to the Commission and the NZAE - there were years when the conference carried little or nothing in the competition / industrial organisation / regulation space, but in the last few years it's had its own regular slot.

The Commission's Ben Harris and Imogen Turner spoke on 'Valuing the harm to consumers in electricity markets'. I'd imagined beforehand that this might have been a go at estimating how much people were missing out by being on inappropriate pricing plans, but it actually looked at the value consumers ascribe to not suffering power outages. Human nature being what it is, people say they'd be hugely put out by an outage inflicted on them. But when offered cold cash to accept an outage, they turn out to take a much lower amount. Funny that. Why does the Commission care? Because the valuation goes into the regulatory regime to prevent the risk of electricity lines companies overbuilding ('gold plating') their asset base and providing levels of reliability that consumers do not actually want. More positively, it feeds into an incentive system rewarding lines companies for better-than-expected outage performance.

Finally Commerce Commissioner John Small took us over 'Empirical analysis on the retail fuel market study' (the study itself is here) and as part of it reminded us of this graph.


The dotted lines are when Z Energy was publishing the 'MPP', "the price that is used at most of Z Energy’s retail sites in the South Island and lower North Island" (market study, p296). The Commission said that, while there could be other explanations, from the graph "it appears that average margins increased during the period when the daily MPP was published, and have levelled off or decreased since publication ceased ... The evidence therefore appears to support our conclusion that the retail market is
conducive to tacit coordination through price transparency and leader-follower pricing" (p298).

The petrol industry is getting close to the pointy end of implementing the recommendations of the market study (a wholesale market, liberalised wholesale supply contracts, publicising the price of 95 octane, and enhanced information provision). My guess would be that the Commission will wait and see how effective they've been, but at some point I'd bet that they will be combing the evidence to see if they've dealt to that "tacit coordination".

Monday, 28 June 2021

So far so good. What next for fiscal policy?

If the Plague had indeed broken out big time last week in Wellington, it would have taken out a high proportion of the country's economists.

No, don't be like that, and put that champagne back in the fridge - fingers crossed, our Sydney visitors don't appear to have spread the pandemic here. But if they had, there was a combo of the Treasury / Reserve Bank workshop on fiscal and monetary policy in the wake of Covid (Tuesday), and the annual shindig of the New Zealand Association of Economists (Wednesday and Thursday, though Thursday got cancelled when Level 2 was brought in). Just about everyone with an interest in macro policy and economic research were all in the same lecture halls at Vic - a very short virus-exposed walk from Rydges Hotel, one of the 'locations of interest'.

Tuesday's workshop (full programme here) kicked off with a keynote, 'New challenges for macroeconomic stabilisation policy: The role of fiscal policy', from Treasury Secretary Caralee McLiesh. What I took away was that we've done well through Covid: as she said (p3) "Overall these [supportive monetary and fiscal policy] interventions, alongside a health response that successfully eliminated COVID-19 in New Zealand, have been effective in supporting the New Zealand economy, which has outperformed our forecasts since the beginning of the pandemic". By international standards we've ended up in a good place, and pushed the fiscal lever hard to get there, as these graphs from her speech show.



Fiscal policy fired up quickly (even if a begrudging part of me wants to add "for once"), and got the support out in literally hours, in some cases, to applicants for wage subsidies. And there's been a corresponding re-assessment of how well fiscal policy can help stabilise an economy against cyclical shocks, with our wage subsidies and the Australians' and Americans' cheques-in-the-mail approaches all clearly effective, and in a timely way.

The supposed pre-Covid consensus that monetary policy was the best cycle stabilisation tool and that fiscal policy would be too lumbering to do any good, has been rather overstated. It was never that clearcut: monetary policy, after all, famously operates through long and variable lags, so isn't necessarily the quick fix some folks touted, and fiscal policy isn't always on a 'turn the first sod in twenty years' Transmission-Gully-style timetable. But in any event the new consensus is that they can both be deployed to good effect early in the piece.

Some commentators see a new, bigger role for fiscal policy as potential over-reach. Michael Reddell in his blog piece on the workshop, 'Fiscal policy in the wake of Covid', felt that "When a half-baked loaf is finished cooking it can be a fine thing, but this loaf seems to need a lot more work before New Zealanders should be rushing to embrace a much more active role for fiscal policy or a lot more public debt". The NZ Initiative's Eric Crampton in 'Govt making the case for higher levels of debt for longer' said that "If the core of the public sector is happy with higher debt levels, despite clear failures in ensuring that funded projects pass any reasonable cost-benefit assessment, greater prudence is needed in how that debt is issued". 

The exact scale and scope of future fiscal activism is still in sum very much up in the air, though if McLiesh is right, and we are indeed headed into a world of permanently lower interest rates, then I hope one outcome is that we pull finger and get on with the overdue infrastructure we need and which have now become significantly cheaper to finance. Which I've been saying for at least the last five years ('A once in a generation opportunity'). 

In  any event you don't have to just sit there and take what's dealt to you in the fullness of time. Treasury is reviewing our macroeconomic frameworks, and you'll get your chance to put in your tuppence worth. There's an e-mail address at the site if you want to get involved.