Thursday, 22 August 2024

CLPINZ 2024

The 35th Annual Workshop of the Competition Law and Policy Institute of New Zealand (CLPINZ) was held last week at the Northern Club in Auckland, and - despite breaching the universally acknowledged convention that every Kiwi conference must at some point offer sausage rolls - was otherwise a well-attended and highly interesting day and a half. Hat tip to the organisers on the Board of CLPINZ and to the indispensable Charlotte Emery at Conference Innovators.

It led off with outgoing CLPINZ chair Anna Ryan introducing the keynote lecture from UCLA's John Asker (UCLA link, personal site, Cornerstone Research site), on 'The Competitive Effects of Information Sharing'. John reminded us that, since at least Hayek, we should think about markets and prices as an immense, efficient, decentralised, information-sharing mechanism for allocating resources, and the integrity of prices really matters for the outcome of the process. But there is a potential tension between the necessary information-sharing in the market, via price signalling, and the possibility of people using the information to collude and undermine the benefit of the free flow of signals. And it's not hard to see real life examples: he cited the case of a Perth-based web-based scheme which had aimed to show each petrol station's prices so that consumers could get the cheapest petrol, but which eventually degenerated into a mechanism enabling the petrol companies to coordinate prices. While some competitive effects can be reasonably obvious, John said that, unlike in areas like mergers where there are known analytical techniques, economics hasn't yet developed the full suite of forensic tools that would enable competition regulators to sort out the sheep from the goats. And when you do apply what tools are available, you don't always get unequivocal answers: his modelling (with coauthors) of timber 'stumpage' auctions, for example, where competitors had information about each others' timber inventories, came up with mixed results: "diagnosing how competition is impacted in non-price information sharing is complicated, and can lead to an outcome where reasonable people might disagree as to whether competition has been adversely impacted".

Keynote speaker John Asker, flanked by session chair Anna Ryan; Fionnghuala Cuncannon as commentator

Commentator Fionnghuala Cuncannon felt that ideally you would like to know when information sharing is harmful, and what is allowed or not under the Commerce Act, and hopefully the Venn diagram of the two ideas would overlap enough to give you a operational basis to act from. On the first point, she agreed with John that deciding on competitive harm is not settled, though in some cases you may well see instances where things look wrong, one example being the price following behaviour based on the 'main port price' that the Commerce Commission noticed in its petrol market study (see for example Figure X3 and paras X35-6). On the second she felt that the Act was "okayish" as it stood, but maybe we could have a think about buttressing it with the likes of the "concerted practices" provisions in s45(1)(c) of Australia's legislation.

Emma Ihaia, the chair of the session on 'Tikanga - is it relevant to Competition Law', introduced it by saying that tikanga is "an area largely unknown to many of us in the room", and that assessment certainly included me: by way of reference for people equally uninformed, Wikipedia says "Tikanga is a Māori term for Māori law, customary law, attitudes and principles, and also for the indigenous legal system which all iwi abided by prior to the colonisation of New Zealand". By the end, we were all a great deal better up with the state of play. Te Aopare Dewes said that use of tikanga is part of a transformational change in Aotearoa New Zealand, that it is now part of our common law post Ellis*, and that it will have relevance for the statutory interpretation of competition law. She also pointed to the Commerce Commission's use of tikanga concepts such as kaitiaki (stewardship, as for example on p13 of the Commission's latest annual report) and its awareness of Māori perspectives in its September 2023 Moana/Sanford merger decision**, although she reckoned the merger would likely have been cleared even without a tikanga lens. The Hon Justice Christian Whata (who headed the Law Commission study which produced the definitive report on the legal dimensions of tikanga) then took us through tikanga as custom, values, and law and talked about "the principles of engagement" which will need to apply as tikanga and European law (if I can call it that) learn to jog along together, including both relevance (tikanga won't affect every matter at issue) and reconciliation (there's no longer a presumption that European law prevails if push comes to shove). And finally Simon Peart took us through some hypothetical case studies the panel had devised to see how the two legal perspectives might or might not play nicely together. One of them (an agreement between otherwise competing Māori fishing companies to place a rāhui on fishing, to conserve the stock, which might amount to output restriction under the cartel provisions of the Commerce Act) didn't look especially problematic: it was fine from the tikanga side and (I'd guess) a strong candidate for authorisation from the Commission's side. The other (one Māori ski operator denying a competitor a licence to operate) was a good deal trickier to reconcile, and reminded us that not all of these issues are going to be a gentle stroll in the park.

The tikanga panel discuss some case studies: L-R, Te Aopare Dewes, Hon Justice Whata, Simon Peart, and session chair (and incoming CLPINZ vice chair) Emma Ihaia

Paul Comrie-Thomson chaired the next one, 'Wellington, we have a problem!', where barrister and incoming CLPINZ chair Ben Hamlin made a convincing case that exemptions from the Commerce Act for "the Crown" are both a legislative mess and poor public policy. Yes, s5 of the Commerce Act binds "the Crown is so far as the Crown engages in trade", but both "the Crown" and "engages in trade" are poorly defined. The Crown (however defined) also has extensive (though nor unfettered) scope to limit competition when not engaged in trade, and as a matter of good public policy it would be better if that scope was subject to some sort of overriding rationale or principle. Ben suggested that "bodies exercising public power should only be able to limit competition where expressly authorised by Parliament, it is reasonably necessary to achieve some public purpose, or it is permitted by a Commission authorisation", and he's drafted a Bill that would legislate along those lines (he's interested in feedback and assistance in polishing it up, so feel free to contact him). In these endeavours Ben was enthusiastically supported by the commentator, Dr Eric Crampton, who pointed to a range of examples of what he regarded as anti-competitive regulation (eg incumbent professionals being allowed to act as the gatekeepers assessing new entrants wanting to ply their trade) and which arise because "The Commerce Act provides broad exceptions for the Crown, particularly in relation to activities that affect commerce but are not considered to be in commerce".

The 2023 workshop had pioneered a new concept, the "Next Generation" session, where rising stars in the competition and regulation world get to strut their stuff, and it worked so well that it was back this year, again chaired by Will Taylor. Russell McVeagh senior solicitor Callum Dickson spoke on 'Privatisation in the space industry': one takeaway was that governments can be quite smart in organising procurement so that they're not at the mercy of a few suppliers or one, in this case suppliers of rocket launching services. Wynn Williams associate Rachael Monkhouse talked about 'The application of competition law to professional sports', where it's evident that sometimes sport gets carved-out treatment that to my eyes at least isn't always defensible. And Houston Kemp economist Nick Twort spoke about 'New analytical tools for understanding retail competition', and in particular the location data that can be cheaply hoovered up from your mobile phone and which can give improved empirical backing for regional market definition, where previously you and I might just have drawn a 5 kilometre circle around an outlet. All good stuff, and while on the topic of up and coming talent, the winner of the inaugural 2024 CLPINZ writing award was Russell McVeagh's Lydia Christensen, with her article, 'Competition Law and the Environment: Climate Change as a Non-Economic Consideration', where she argues that the Commission "has failed to genuinely engage with climate change factors as non-economic considerations that ought to be balanced against other factors".

Will Taylor (L) introduces the Next Gen speakers: L-R, Callum Dickson, Rachael Monkhouse, Nick Twort

Saturday morning brought us 'Settlement of IP disputes', chaired by Otago Professor Ed Willis and presented in case study format by barristers Earl Gray and John Land. Their argument was that since the the expansion of the definition of a cartel in the 2017 changes to the Commerce Act to specifically mention collusive output restriction, agreements in intellectual property disputes to stop producing things that infringe copyright or patents are at risk of being pinged as a cartel, and the risk is all the more real after the Moola*** case. Their solution is an amendment to the Act (which they have drafted and is ready to go) which would exempt good faith settlements in genuine disputes from the ambit of s30 cartel conduct. We need to be wary of anything that might open the door to the rather despicable 'pay for delay' sham patent settlements we've seen in overseas pharmaceutical markets, but that said, I can see the issue that confronts genuine settlements. Part of me wonders about the legal reasoning - how can it be an output restriction if the output allegedly restricted could never have been legally produced in the first place? - but when I asked the question, it didn't seem to cut any ice with my learned friends in the law. I also got the distinct impression that the Commission would be unlikely to bestir itself in cases where, on the facts, like in Earl and John's dairy packaging machinery example, there's clearly no collusive anti-competitive intent.

Finally we got to what Anna Ryan later described as "almost a second keynote address", and it was: Danielle Wood, chair of the Australian Productivity Commission, spoke on 'Competition Policy: Back in Fashion?', in a session chaired by her former colleague Hayden Green. In Australia, the answer to her question is, absolutely yes: they are pressing on with further reform (after two thorough previous goes, the 'Hilmer' and 'Harper' reviews), with their current rolling well-resourced Competition Review and its Expert Advisory Panel (of which Danielle is a member, as is John Asker) and which has already produced draft M&A legislation to address eg 'killer' and 'creeping' acquisitions. It is also tackling other good ideas, including addressing the epidemic of non-compete agreements which is anticompetitively blighting labour market mobility, and working on the next instalment of a National Competition Policy (programmes of reform agreed between the Federal and State governments) which might encompass things like easing parallel import restrictions. The Productivity Commission itself has further useful things on the go, such as liberalising occupational licencing. If you don't have access to the CLPINZ workshop materials, Danielle reprised her presentation in the latest of Treasury's guest lectures, and you'll find both a video and the slides here.

(L) Danielle Wood, chair of the Australian Productivity Commission, and (R) commentator Catherine Montague, manager of competition policy at MBIE

The commentator was Catherine Montague, manager of competition policy at MBIE, speaking in a personal capacity rather than presenting a ministry or government view. She suggested that there was potential impetus for reform in New Zealand, based on the current government's focus on productivity, the example of the Aussies, and the rark-up we got from the OECD in Chapter 3 of their latest economic survey of New Zealand (from the Executive Summary, "Insufficient competition is an important factor underpinning low productivity ... more can and should be done to further improve competition outcomes"). While nothing's yet settled, potential candidates for attention are mergers ('creeping' mergers, amending the SLC test to specify that it would include entrenching market power, and aligning with wherever Aussie gets to), non-competes and other restraints in the labour market, ensuring more attention is given to the competition effect of policy changes, and implementing a Consumer Data Right. 

Fingers crossed that something like this agenda happens, and sooner rather than later: recent experience has unfortunately been that we have been too timid in scope and process, much too slow, and decidedly belated. Either MBIE or our new Ministry for Regulation would be well advised to take a leaf from the Aussie textbook and get on with something similar to their latest Competition Review, and if we're interested in alignment with our friends across the ditch, a couple of cross-appointments (like the ones the ACCC and the Commerce Commission already operate) wouldn't go amiss, either.

*Ellis v R [2022] NZSC 114, [2022] 1 NZLR 239

**The final clearance decision doesn't seem to have been loaded into the Commission's online case register

*** Commerce Commission v Moola.co.nz Ltd [2021] NZHC 3423